laitimes

Good book recommendation: Thirty years later, has Japan come out of the deflationary trap?

author:Pick up

In the 90s of the last century, Japan's bubble economy burst. Since then, Japan has entered an "era of deflation" that has lasted for 30 years. How to get rid of deflation has become an important issue for the Japanese government in the long run.

In the wake of the pandemic, the global inflation, which had once become history, hit hard and had an impact on Japan. Since 2022, there has been a lot of news about rising food prices in Japan, and the price system has changed a lot, but deflation is still the biggest problem for people living in Japan, and prices have risen, but wages have not risen.

Japan may be at the brink of the worst, and at a crossroads where it needs to make a choice.

In his new book "Inflation or Deflation: The Myth of the Global Economy", renowned Japanese scholar No. Watanabe provides a new perspective on understanding Japan's deflationary predicament, and expounds the unique opportunities and great challenges facing Japan in the era of great inflation by analyzing Japan's policy measures to deal with deflation. It provides an important reference for China to stabilize economic growth and prevent inflation and deflation.

Part 1:

How has the wage-price paradigm hindered Japan's development?

Since the mid-90s of the 20th century, when the economy fell into a trough, Japan has had extremely low prices for 1/4 century, with prices for goods and services almost unchanged.

And all of this stems from the change in consumer expectations. Consumers are worried that the financial crisis will trigger job losses and they are starting to save money. In this process, consumers are more sensitive to prices, and companies do not dare to raise the price of their products, and all operators adopt conservative strategies and freeze wages. Based on this consideration, both prices and wages suddenly stopped rising against the background at that time.

However, in the 21st century, Japan's economy has entered a boom channel, but prices and wages are still low and frozen, and this state continues to this day. This is no accident, for consumers, if wages are frozen and prices rise, daily life will be unsustainable; For companies, if wages rise and product prices remain unchanged, business operations will also be in trouble, so it is not feasible to freeze prices without freezing wages. As a result, prices and wages were frozen at the same time, which was considered an "equilibrium compromise point" between the two.

The reality is that consumers want to raise wages and companies want to raise the price of their products, but if no one is doing so, it is a good idea to keep both sides the same. It is for this reason that the wage and price freeze has persisted to this day.

For the Japanese, it has become the norm for the price of products not to rise, and it is a matter of course. According to this common sense, if you find that a store that shops frequently has an increase in price, people will usually think that the price increase must be caused by some special factor, and that other stores may not increase their price without a special reason. Since it is expected that other stores will be cheaper, it is natural that they will not buy goods with increased prices at the original store, but will turn around and buy at other stores.

Not only are Japanese consumers not expecting price increases, but Japanese companies are also aware of this, and they are reluctant to raise product prices even if there is an increase in raw material prices. The coexistence of consumers' "hateful price increases" and companies' "price freeze practices" has become a matter of course for people living in Japan.

This kind of society is naturally called a "social norm" in economics, and the phenomenon that prices and wages should be frozen is called the Japanese "wage price paradigm." When former Japanese Prime Minister Shinzo Abe was in office, he launched a package of financial, fiscal and economic structural reforms in an attempt to change the mindset of the Japanese people. At the heart of this package is the Bank of Japan's epoch-making quantitative easing monetary policy. In other words, it sends a strong signal that the money supply will continue to increase not only now but also in the future.

The epoch-making monetary easing policy did lead to a sharp depreciation of the yen, but when the effect of the policy spread to rising prices, the Japanese people began to complain that the price had risen without raising wages, and as a result, the paradigm reform had failed.

Part 2:

After the pandemic, new opportunities are coming for Japan?

At the beginning of 2020, the world was suddenly threatened by a novel viral pandemic. Our lives were immediately changed, with economic activity rapidly stalling and the global economy plunging into a rapid recession. The outbreak of the pandemic has challenged the economic system in a completely different paradigm, paralyzing the global logistics network built by the rapid development of economic globalization in the 21st century, cutting off the global supply chain network and causing global product prices to rise.

However, real inflation did not come at the same time as the pandemic, but there is a certain time lag. In the wake of the pandemic, the behavior of workers and consumers has not returned to business as expected, but has gone off track. For example, employees who are accustomed to working remotely are refusing to return to their old factories or offices, and consumer behavior is changing unexpectedly. In order to avoid crowded places, or to maintain physical distance from others, our lifestyles have changed. In line with this, where and what is consumed has changed. Those products that consumers consume intensively have caused prices to rise due to insufficient production capacity.

After the pandemic, the expectations of the Japanese people regarding inflation have changed. Japan's Cabinet Office conducts a monthly "Consumption Trend Survey" of about 8,400 households, which also includes an option for the expected inflation rate in the coming year. According to the survey results, the increase in inflation expectations, which began in the fall of 2020, has increased by 4% so far. Real inflation rose 3.5% over the same period, suggesting that expected inflation is rising faster than actual inflation.

Japanese companies are also considering changing their actions when their inflation expectations have risen and their mentality of hating price increases has changed. The reason why companies did not raise prices before was because they were worried that the price increase would lose customers, but now they don't have to worry so much about customer loss, and they may change the practice of freezing prices. While consumers have to accept higher prices, this is unsustainable without a change in the wage freeze. The fundamental solution to the paradigm is to abandon the practice of "prices and wages remain unchanged" and shift to a paradigm in which "prices and wages are rising."

In fact, Japan is now at a fork in the road, and there are two paths ahead: one is to continue to maintain the current paradigm and have a stagflationary situation; The other is to turn to the same paradigm as European and American countries and return to normal countries. If we follow the first path, prices begin to rise without changing wages, and the real purchasing power of workers falls, the only way to survive is to thrive. As a result, people's consumption has declined, and the growth of GDP growth has also decreased.

At the moment, Japan has the opportunity to develop along the second path. Inflation expectations have increased, and consumers' aversion to price increases has begun to improve, and Japanese consumers have become not much different from their European and American counterparts. Now it's the turn of the business to act. The ability of companies to confidently pass on the cost burden to product prices is the primary obstacle to ending the practice of not raising prices.

Another obstacle is whether companies can be proactive in raising wages. For this problem, companies are not only slow to act, but also very pessimistic about the future wage increase expectations, compared with Europe and the United States. It is still impossible to tell where Japanese society will go in the future, but there is no doubt that Japan is facing a major choice that has not been seen in decades.

Part 3:

How can Japan break out of the wage-price spiral?

A wage-price spiral refers to a process in which rising wages lead to rising prices, which in turn prompt workers to demand higher wages. Such a process could lead to an increase in inflation, affecting economic stability and development.

For Japan, inflation is still low, and there is no need to worry about a spiral of wages and prices, but this is not to say that Japan has nothing to do with this wage-price spiral.

The most important feature of the wage-price spiral that European and American countries are worried about is the self-realization mechanism of inflation expectations, which also appears in the Japanese-style spiral model, that is, the reason why workers do not ask for a wage increase is that the expected inflation rate is zero, and because the wage rises to zero, the capitation fee does not change, and the company decides not to raise the price, so that the inflation expectation of workers determines the actual inflation rate through the actions of workers and companies. This mechanism is the same as the orthodox spiraling mechanism.

The wage-price spiral in Europe and the United States can adopt monetary tightening to cool overheated demand, which is the orthodox treatment. But cooling demand will be accompanied by an increase in unemployment, and excessive unemployment costs may be beyond the capacity of society. In this situation, policy objectives have to be changed, and what needs to be considered is the direct regulation of wages and prices, which is the "alternative" treatment for heretics.

The same is true of the Japanese-style wage-price spiral, which is first adjusted according to the orthodox treatment plan, except that Japan stimulates demand, and for this it needs to lower interest rates. As interest rates fall, the unemployment rate will be lowered, so there is no need to worry about the unemployment rate seriously exceeding the social capacity as in Europe and the United States. But orthodox treatment options also have limitations, that is, the limitation of lower interest rates, negative interest rates cannot be reduced to any desired extent. Once the lower bound is reached, interest rates cannot continue to fall, and demand cannot continue to be stimulated. This is the situation when interest rates in Japan fell to zero around 2000.

Due to the limitations of orthodox treatment options, Japan had to turn to "alternative" treatment options for heresy. Because the situation in Japan is that wages and prices are frozen, what Japan needs is not direct control of wages and prices, but an "unfreeze". In Japan, we will take action based on the expectation of "achieving the 2% inflation target set by the Bank of Japan" as an expectation shared by all stakeholders. First, workers or unions demand a wage increase consistent with the 2% inflation rate, and secondly, the company accepts the workers' demand for a wage increase and increases the price of the product according to the increase in the capitation fee, so that the inflation rate of 2% can be achieved.

One of the hardest aspects of this chain of actions is stakeholders sharing 2% inflation expectations and acting accordingly, which is also a problem faced by countries with traditional spirals. For example, workers are not asking for a wage increase that is consistent with a 2% price increase

(and still remain the same as before), companies will not raise the price of their products, this is due to the fact that when consumers are short on their hands, once a price increase is proposed, the business will lose customers. On the other hand, if the company cannot raise the price by 2% and the price remains unchanged, it will not be able to accept the employee's request for a wage increase, and even if the employee asks for a wage increase, the company will have to reject the employee's request for a wage increase, realizing that the profit will deteriorate, and the employee's insistence on making a strong request for a wage increase may endanger the employee's job.

Whether Japan can seize the period of great global change, break the "wage-price spiral model", and achieve a wage thaw has reached a critical juncture.

Book Recommendations:

Good book recommendation: Thirty years later, has Japan come out of the deflationary trap?

"Inflation or Deflation" tells the real cause of rising prices around the world and its impact on consumers, workers and businesses from the perspective of the "post-pandemic era".

In addition to describing the changing situation in the world economy, the book also analyzes Japan's special difficulties in both deflation and global inflation. In addition, the book explores how central banks respond to the problem of high prices and their limitations, giving readers a global perspective on economic analysis.

- end -

Swipe up and down to read more

安 昀 | 鲍无可 | 包承超 | 贲兴振 | 薄官辉 | 毕天宇曹 晋 | 曹 霞 | 曹文俊 | 常亚桥 | 常 蓁 | 常 远崔建波 | 陈璇淼 | 陈一峰 | 陈 栋 | 陈 平 | 陈 媛陈立秋 | 陈 军 | 陈觉平 | 陈 浩 | 陈文扬 | 陈 宇陈金伟 | 陈国光 | 陈思靖 | 陈 鹏 | 陈 玮 | 陈乐天陈轶平 | 陈良栋 | 陈连权 | 陈怀逸 | 陈圆明 | 陈 文成念良 | 程 彧 | 程 洲 | 程 琨 | 程 涛 | 崔 莹蔡嵩松 | 蔡 滨 | 蔡 晓 | 蔡志鹏 | 蔡志文 | 丁靖斐代云峰 | 邓炯鹏 | 董伟炜 | 董 超 | 董 梁 | 杜晓海杜 洋 | 杜 沛 | 杜 广 | 冯明远 | 傅奕翔 | 付 斌付 娟 | 付伟琦 | 费 逸 | 范 洁 | 范庭芳 | 方钰涵方 纬 | 方 抗 | 方 建 | 方 昶 | 高兰君 | 高 远刚登峰 | 葛 晨 | 顾耀强 | 顾益辉 | 谷琦彬 | 归 凯管嘉琪 | 郭 锐 | 郭 堃 | 郭相博 | 巩怀志 | 韩 冬韩海平 | 韩 冰 | 韩 林 | 郝旭东 | 郝 淼 | 何 帅何晓春 | 何 琦 | 何以广 | 贺 喆 | 霍东杰 | 侯振新侯 梧 | 侯 杰 | 洪 流 | 胡昕炜 | 胡鲁滨 | 胡宜斌胡 涛 | 胡 伟 | 胡志利 | 胡 喆 | 胡 颖 | 黄 峰黄 力 | 黄立华 | 黄 波 | 黄 晧 | 黄垲锐 | 黄莹洁黄立图 | 姜 诚 | 姜 英 | 蒋 鑫 | 蒋 璆 | 江 勇江 琦 | 江 虹 | 纪文静 | 焦 巍 | 贾 鹏 | 贾 腾金晟哲 | 金笑非 | 金梓才 | 季新星 | 季 鹏 | 匡 伟孔令超 | 阚 磊 | 劳杰男 | 蓝小康 | 雷 鸣 | 雷 敏雷志勇 | 李德辉 | 李 琛 | 李晓西 | 李晓星 | 李元博李耀柱 | 李玉刚 | 李健伟 | 李 建 | 李佳存 | 李 巍李 竞 | 李 君 | 李振兴 | 李 欣 | 李少君 | 李 瑞李文宾 | 李 彪 | 李宜璇 | 李子波 | 李 倩 | 李 燕李 崟 | 厉叶淼 | 黎海威 | 廉赵峰 | 梁 浩 | 梁 辉梁 力 | 梁永强 | 梁文涛 | 梁 鹏 | 廖瀚博 | 林 庆林剑平 | 林 森 | 刘 斌 | 刘 波 | 刘 冬 | 刘 辉银华刘 辉东方红 | 刘格菘 | 刘 江 | 刘莉莉 | 刘晓龙刘 苏 | 刘 锐东方红 | 刘 锐中信保诚 | 刘 平 | 刘 潇刘 兵 | 刘 晓 | 刘开运 | 刘元海 | 刘心任 | 刘志辉刘伟伟 | 刘 鹏 | 刘宇涛 | 柳世庆 | 柳万军 | 陆 彬陆政哲 | 陆 欣 | 陆 航 | 陆 奔 | 陆文凯 | 罗春蕾罗世锋 | 罗佳明 | 罗远航 | 骆 莹 | 吕佳玮 | 吕越超闾志刚 | 楼慧源 | 马 翔 | 马 龙 | 毛从容 | 莫海波苗 宇 | 闵良超 | 牛 勇 | 倪权生 | 农冰立 | 彭凌志彭成军 | 潘中宁 | 潘 明 | 蒲世林 | 齐 皓 | 祁 禾邱璟旻 | 邱世磊 | 丘栋荣 | 邱 杰 | 钱伟华 | 钱亚风云秦 毅 | 秦绪文 | 曲 径 | 饶 刚 | 任琳娜 | 桑 磊宋海岸 | 宋 华 | 岁 寒 | 石海慧 | 石 波 | 沈 楠沈雪峰 | 史 伟 | 是星涛 | 苏谋东 | 苏俊杰 | 孙 芳孙 伟民生加银 | 孙 伟东方红 | 孙轶佳 | 孙浩中 | 孙梦祎孙 蒙 | 邵 卓 | 盛震山 | 唐颐恒 | 唐 华 | 提云涛汤 慧 | 谭冬寒 | 谭鹏万 | 谭 丽 | 田彧龙 | 田 瑀田宏伟 | 屠环宇 | 陶 灿 | 万建军 | 王大鹏 | 王东杰王 刚 | 王君正 | 王 涵 | 王 俊 | 王 培 | 王 鹏王 栩 | 王延飞 | 王宗合 | 王克玉 | 王 景 | 王诗瑶王晓明 | 王奇玮 | 王筱苓 | 王园园 | 王 垠 | 王文祥王 睿中银 | 王 睿中信保诚 | 王海涛 | 王登元 | 王 健王德伦 | 王艺伟 | 王浩冰 | 王 斌 | 王晓宁 | 王 浩魏晓雪 | 魏 东 | 魏建榕 | 韦明亮 | 翁启森 | 吴 星吴 达 | 吴培文 | 吴丰树 | 吴 印 | 吴 渭 | 吴 越吴 弦 | 吴 坚 | 吴 悠 | 伍 旋 | 武 杰 | 肖瑞瑾肖威兵 | 肖 觅 | 谢书英 | 谢振东 | 徐荔蓉 | 徐志敏徐 成 | 徐 斌 | 徐 博 | 徐志华 | 徐习佳 | 徐 爽许文星 | 许 炎 | 许望伟 | 许利明 | 薛冀颖 | 夏 雨颜 媛 | 闫 旭 | 杨 栋 | 杨 浩 | 杨 瑨 | 杨锐文杨 帆 | 杨岳斌 | 杨 明 | 杨 飞 | 杨晓斌 | 杨 鹏杨 梦 | 杨立春 | 姚 跃 | 姚志鹏 | 叶 松 | 叶 展易智泉 | 易小金 | 于 渤 | 于 洋 | 于善辉 | 于浩成于 鹏 | 俞晓斌 | 袁 宜 | 袁 航 | 袁 曦 | 袁多武袁争光 | 余小波 | 余芽芳 | 余科苗 | 张丹华 | 张东一张 凯 | 张 峰富国 | 张 峰农银汇理 | 张 锋 | 张汉毅张 晖 | 张 慧 | 张金涛 | 张 骏 | 张剑峰 | 张 萍张 帆 | 张延鹏 | 张迎军 | 张益驰 | 张鸿羽 | 张 弘张 航 | 张 寓 | 张宇帆 | 张 杨 | 张 堃 | 张仲维张 勋 | 张 靖 | 张 亮 | 张西林 | 张晓龙 | 张浩佳张亚辉 | 张 英 | 张 明 | 章 恒 | 章 晖 | 章旭峰章秀奇 | 章鸽武 | 詹 成 | 赵大震 | 赵晓东 | 赵 强赵 剑 | 赵浩添 | 赵 伟 | 曾 刚 | 郑澄然 | 郑慧莲郑 科 | 郑 磊 | 郑巍山 | 郑 伟 | 郑泽鸿 | 郑 日郑 宁 | 周 晶 | 周应波 | 周克平 | 周 良 | 周雪军周 云 | 周 杨 | 周 崟 | 周寒颖 | 周智硕 | 周文群朱 平 | 朱 赟 | 朱晓亮 | 钟 赟 | 钟 帅 | 朱 熠左金保 | 赵 蓓 | 智 健 | 邹立虎 | 邹维娜 | 邹 唯邹 曦

Good book recommendation: Thirty years later, has Japan come out of the deflationary trap?
Good book recommendation: Thirty years later, has Japan come out of the deflationary trap?

Read on